Sections

Commentary

What happens to health financing during the middle-income transition?

A health worker walks between parked ambulances at the Avenue hospital in Nairobi, Kenya February 1, 2019. Picture taken February 1, 2019. REUTERS/Baz Ratner - RC15F30A3BC0

As countries move from low to middle income, they experience big shifts in the composition of public and private spending on health. One reason for the change in financing is the eligibility criteria for concessional development assistance: Foreign aid starts to decrease after countries move into middle income. This is evident from a snapshot of health expenditures across the income spectrum, used to proxy what happens to a country as its per capita income increases. Figure 1 charts health expenditures by source for countries organized from lowest to highest GDP per capita in year 2015; charts for 2000, 2005, and 2010 look similar. The black vertical lines mark the gross national income (GNI) per capita thresholds for low, lower-middle, upper-middle and high income, revised annually by the World Bank.

Much of the drop in external financing for health happens during lower-middle income, namely per capita gross national incomes between roughly $1,000 and $4,000. By the time a developing country has a per capita income of $5,000, it should expect little or no assistance for health care from abroad (the dark green segment in Figure 1).

Figure 1: Composition of health spending in low-, middle-, and high-income economies, 2015

Figure 1: Composition of health spending in low-, middle-, and high-income economies, 2015Note: Figure 1 shows, for countries arranged by per capita output, the four main sources of health expenditures as a percentage of current health expenditures (CHE): domestic general government health expenditure (GGHE-D), external health expenditures (EXT), out-of-pocket health expenditures by households (OOP), and private domestic health expenditures (PVT) that include a variety of prepaid and voluntary payment mechanisms.

Lower-middle income—a time of big changes

The other change during the lower-middle income phase is in the share of health care financed by government spending, which increases from about a fifth to more than a third of total health costs (in light green). It continues to increase in upper-middle income. By the time a country is a high-income economy—a per capita gross national income of more than $12,500—this ratio is about half.

The relative importance of the other two components of health care financing—private arrangements (in yellow in Figure 1) and out-of-pocket spending (in blue)—remains roughly unchanged during middle income. Indeed, the share of private health spending through insurance schemes is pretty much the same in low-, middle-, and high-income countries.

This is how the composition of health care finance changes when a country reaches lower-middle income. What happens to the actual amounts? Figure 2 shows per capita health spending for all lower-middle income countries (LMICs) in 2015 arranged from lowest to highest GDP per capita. External per capita health spending essentially stays at about $20, hence falling by about 75 percent relative to income. Per capita public expenditures and out-of-pocket spending increase sixfold, outstripping the increase in incomes. Out-of-pocket expenditures stay higher than domestic public health spending throughout lower-middle income; reductions in the importance of out-of-pocket spending actually happen well after a country reaches advanced economy status.

Figure 2: Per capita health spending in lower-middle income countries, 2015

Figure 2: Per capita health spending in lower-middle income countries, 2015Source: Author calculations.

In summary, the stylized facts are that during the transition through middle-income, increases in domestic government spending start to replace foreign developmental assistance, and government spending increases to substitute for out-of-pocket spending only in high-income economies. The question that should concern policymakers, development agencies, and donors is whether and how this can be changed. Put another way, can middle-income country governments both pay more and stimulate the growth of reliable and less regressive private arrangements?

Public preparedness in middle-income countries

The transition policies of different multilateral and bilateral donors vary widely. Eligibility conditions for aid vary across donors based on parameters such as disease incidence, coverage rates, and other features of the health care system. But the cutoff generally kicks in when a country crosses into lower-middle income. As donors start to leave, LMIC governments are expected to start funding health programs themselves. This means mobilizing more taxes and contributions, to make up for declining grant financing and to service more borrowing by the government.

Previous analysis by Duke University’s Center for Policy Impact in Global Health has documented that the increment in taxes and contributions in the transition from lower- to upper-middle income levels is small. While the average per capita GDP of the typical upper-middle income economy is nearly triple that of the average lower-middle income country, the average ratio of taxes and contributions to GDP increases by just 4 percentage points. The analysis also suggests that increases in foreign aid are associated with lower revenue mobilization in low and lower-middle income countries. Governments and donors should worry when external financing is inadvertently structured to weaken domestic resource mobilization efforts. The result is that LMIC governments often have neither enough money nor capacity.

Figure 3: Few lower-middle income governments provide adequate financing for health care

Figure 3: Few lower-middle income governments provide adequate financing for healthcareNote: Numbers are for 2015; in 2019, the World Bank reclassified Sri Lanka as an upper middle-income economy.
Source: World Development Indicators.

This problem has not escaped notice. In 2000, for example, the leaders of the African Union pledged to dedicate 15 percent of government spending to the health sector. Using this as a benchmark, most LMICs fall far short. On average, LMICs with higher incomes do spend almost four times as much as the poorer countries, but there can be big differences between countries with similar per capita incomes. In our current work, we are looking more closely at six countries that span the lower-middle income spectrum: Kenya, Myanmar, Ghana, India, Nigeria, and Sri Lanka (upper-middle income since July 1, 2019).

Improving health care finance during the middle-income transition

Whether or not the structural changes in public spending that we see are good or bad for people in middle-income countries is still a matter of debate. The persistently high share of out-of-pocket expenditures across the middle-income transition suggests much room for improvement. Financial risk protection is a high priority in the progress towards universal health care. The question is how developing countries can put in place systems that are robust in the face of deficits in coverage and financing, donor exits, changing diseases, and evolving demographics.

Duke University’s Center for Policy Impact in Global Health is partnering with think tanks and universities in sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia to better understand health financing and delivery in countries at various stages of transition from donor financing. The research aims to untangle the interconnected issues in disease, demography, development assistance, and domestic finance (the “4Ds”) in six countries and assess their preparedness to move from donor support to domestic finance. Some of the questions that we are trying to answer:

  • Donor transitions. How do major donors determine aid eligibility, how does this support evolve during middle-income, and what are the shifts in donor and government strategies that have led to smoother transitions?
  • Pocket problems. Given serious social and spatial inequities in middle-income economies, how can donors align their work with national and state governments to make out-of-pocket spending less regressive and aggressively target pockets of poor health?
  • Plugging gaps. To respond effectively to changing diseases and demographics during middle-income, how can the critical knowledge, capacity, and policy gaps in health financing be closed?

We plan to report our results in a series of posts on this blog.

Authors