Sections
Editor's note:

This piece was updated on June 4, 2022 to clarify the authors’ anti-inflationary estimate.

Inflation has recently emerged as the top economic concern in the U.S. The Federal Reserve is now raising interest rates in an attempt to curb inflation, but their job would be easier, and the risk of a recession reduced, if we could directly address some of the job market bottlenecks that are contributing to inflation. This phenomenon has been called “the Great Resignation” – where there are too few workers to fill currently available jobs – because some have left the labor market, while others are reluctant to accept or keep jobs there. The aging of the U.S. population and a recent decline in immigration compound these effects.

In his Wall Street Journal op-ed on May 31, President Biden listed a number of ways to reduce inflation – and one of them was cutting the cost of child care to families, so that the parents of small children could more easily enter the workforce. Indeed, his Build Back Better (BBB) agenda included policies such as greater access to child care and universal pre-K for all 3- and 4-year-olds, policies with the potential to boost labor supply and potentially reduce inflation. That legislation remains in limbo because of the opposition of Senator Joe Manchin (D-WV). But if it had been enacted a year ago, it could have made a difference – not just to the well-being of families and children but even to the inflationary pressures that have now emerged, pressures fueled in part by a lack of workers to produce the products and services people want.

To be sure, the war in Ukraine, supply-chain problems, and earlier stimulus packages such as the American Rescue Plan (which left many consumers with extra cash) are part of the problem. But what’s happening in the labor market is almost unprecedented. Employers simply cannot find enough workers. Reported job vacancies now exceed the number of unemployed workers by over 5 million. That is forcing employers to raise wages and prices, adding to inflation. As Domash and Summers (2022) have shown, vacancy rates are very highly correlated with inflation and are currently the highest on record since the series began in 2000.

One way to address the problem is to entice more women off the sidelines and back into the labor force. Many of them dropped out of the labor force during the pandemic, and their employment still falls further short of pre-pandemic levels than does employment among men. But the U.S. has a longer-term problem, unrelated to the pandemic. Compared to other advanced nations, women work less in the U.S. and that’s partly because the U.S. provides so little support for child care, early education, and paid leave. With more such supports, more women would work, producing more of what people want, and potentially limiting inflationary pressures.

In this brief, we examine this issue in an attempt to determine whether and how much reducing child care costs might reduce overall inflation. We come to three conclusions.

First, we believe that more child care of the kind proposed in Build Back Better would increase female labor force participation and raise the nation’s output and income. Had it been enacted last year, and fully paid for, it might also have reduced inflationary pressures somewhat by allowing more women to remain in the labor market and easing worker shortages this year and in 2023-24. However, our rough calculations suggest that any such effects would likely be very modest. One reason is because any increase in the number of people at work would be partly offset by extra spending out of newly earned income. More importantly, as we argue below, fighting inflation is not the primary reason to enact such legislation.

Second, and on a more positive note, we show that the kind of child care subsidies included in the Build Back Better legislation would have had a big impact on family budgets and well-being by reducing existing child care expenses, especially for the most disadvantaged, thereby freeing up income for other purposes – including offsetting the effects that inflation is having on these families’ budgets.

Third, and over the longer run, we show that child care policies and pre-K, by increasing female employment, would spur more economic activity. This added activity would provide families with greater income and governments with a little more revenue. Combined with new investments in the quality of child care and in pre-K, the Build Back Better proposals could also improve the life trajectories of children, and their future productivity and incomes as well.

Female Labor Force Participation

Women’s participation in the labor market changed fairly little between 2000 and 2019. It then declined sharply during the pandemic as shown in Figure 1 and has subsequently recovered although, at this writing, not to its pre-pandemic level in 2019.

During the pandemic, between February 2020 and February 2022, the labor force participation of women fell by 1.3 percentage points while that of men fell by 1.0 percentage point. Many analysts (e.g., Albanesi and Kim, 2021) attribute the impact of the pandemic on women’s employment primarily to their greater responsibilities for the care of children. With schools and child care centers closed, many women had little choice but to remain at home. Some left the labor force and may now be reconsidering the decision of whether or not to work – in fact, about half of workers report they are rethinking the job they want post-pandemic. The pandemic was a wake-up call on the importance of women’s employment to the health of the economy and to the role of schools and child care centers in making their contributions possible.

Women are now the primary breadwinners in over 40 percent of all families. Many are single parents, and the rest are married but make more money than their husbands or partners. Even before the pandemic, women faced a serious “time squeeze” because of their dual roles as breadwinners and caregivers. In fact, virtually all of the increase in real middle-class incomes over the past four decades was due to women entering the labor force and earning more as they moved up the occupational ladder. In the absence of their earnings, real middle-class incomes (incomes for the middle 60 percent of the population) would have stagnated over those four decades (Figure 2). In sum, women have become essential to a family’s economic well-being.

Figure 2: Growth in average middle-class income that is due to women’s earnings

As women’s entry into the workforce slowed in America after 2000, participation rates continued to rise in other advanced economies as shown in Figure 3, with the result that other countries now have rates that are 5 to 8 percentage points higher than in the U.S.

Of 22 OECD member countries, U.S. prime-age female participation fell from 6th to 21st between 1990 and 2020. While there are many possible reasons for the higher participation rates of women in some other countries, the biggest difference between the United States and our international counterparts is probably the lack of family-friendly policies. The U.S. is the only advanced democracy without a statutory federal right to paid leave; it provides very low levels of support for child care and early education, and it expects employees to work longer hours per year than in most of Europe. Looking at child care subsidies as a proportion of GDP, the U.S. ranks 35th out of 37 countries according to the OECD. In terms of investments in pre-K, it ranks below 40 other countries.

For these reasons, it is not surprising that women in the U.S. have greater difficulty meeting the competing demands of the workplace and the family. Blau and Kahn (2013) find that America’s lack of family-friendly policies can explain almost 30 percent of the shortfall in women’s participation between 1990 and 2010 relative to other OECD countries.

Child Care

In 2016, 40 percent of children under the age of 6 were cared for by their parents while the other 60 percent were in a variety of care arrangements, with most paying for this care.

Child care is very expensive. On average, a family has to pay 18 percent of their income for an infant and 13 percent for a toddler in licensed care. The monthly cost varies from about $800 to about $1200 for children under 6, with infants costing more than preschoolers. High quality licensed care – meaning care in which salaries are aligned with kindergarten teacher compensation and in which staff/child ratios and group sizes are consistent with best practice in the field, costs even more: from $1500 to $2200 per month.

Child care is not just expensive but often hard to find, especially for those with nonstandard hours or living in “child care deserts.” Given the costs and the difficulties of finding good care, many mothers choose not to work, or work only part-time. For these reasons, we believe more women would work, or work additional hours, if more high-quality child care and other supports such as paid leave were available. Indeed, the research literature supports this view and we discuss the evidence in more detail below.

It should be noted that any increase in demand is likely to raise the costs of care, especially if it is high quality. Right now, child care workers are in short supply. Without more infrastructure and a better-paid child care workforce, it will be hard to scale up the existing system in line with any new demand without a further deterioration in quality. For that reason, any ramp-up in government spending on child care needs to also include investments in the child care work force and the supply of facilities. The Biden proposal does include such investments, but we are cognizant of the fact that those investments will take time to bear fruit and that any downward effect of higher labor force participation on inflation could be partially offset by potential bottlenecks in the child care sector itself as well as by any increase in spending on the part of families induced by their higher earnings.

Relatedly, pre-K slots are also in short supply. Although 44 states now provide some kind of pre-K program it is not always full-day or available to three-year-olds. The result is that about half of 3- and 4-year-olds remain unserved with children from lower-income families the least likely to be enrolled. Although there is still some controversy about the effects of both pre-K and child care on child development, most researchers believe that high-quality programs lead to better outcomes later in life, such as an increase in high school and college graduation rates, and higher earnings. And whatever the effects of early education and care on child outcomes, it enables more women to work and thus brings more income into the family.

Build Back Better

By calling for more paid leave, preschool, and child care, the Build Back Better bill aimed to make it easier for women to combine work and caring for their families, reduce the strain of child care costs on families, and to support the healthy development of children.

The Biden child care proposal provides subsidies to parents using any form of licensed care. The amount of the subsidy varies with income. The formula is complex and depends on family size and state of residence, but child care would essentially be free for families below about $75,000 in annual income and phase out entirely for those with incomes above about $250,000. No family would have to pay more than 7 percent of their income for child care. The program requires states to opt in and to pick up a share of the costs with the state share rising over time.

As detailed below, we estimate that the proposal will cut child care costs by nearly two-thirds. When we add in the fact that pre-K will be free for three and four-year-olds, and that they represent about a third of all children under 6 (and about one-sixth of those not currently enrolled), the costs of care are further reduced.

Predicted Impacts of Biden Child Care Plan on Labor Force Activity, GDP and Inflation

By how much would the Biden child care plan have reduced inflation if it had been enacted when it was first proposed in the fall of 2021? And by how much could new subsidies for child care still help to contain inflation while increasing labor force participation and income for families with children?

We begin with its likely impact on labor force activity and GDP, which we can predict with some confidence and accuracy; we then speculate about its possible effects on inflation.

Labor Force and GDP

Table 1 contains the results of our calculations on how Biden’s plan would affect labor force activity and GDP. First, we draw two estimates from the literature on the elasticity of maternal labor supply with respect to a reduction in child care costs. The first estimate is the midpoint of a range of estimates in a paper by Taryn Morrissey (2017), which reviews various estimates of the elasticity of maternal labor supply with respect to child care in the U.S. and abroad over several decades; the likely range in her paper is .05 to .25, and so the midpoint is .15 – implying that a 10 percent reduction in child care costs would raise maternal employment (total hours worked) by 1.5 percent. The second elasticity estimate is drawn from a recent paper by the National Women’s Law Center and The Center for Social Policy at Columbia University, and it is approximately .25.

Table 1: Predicted Effects of Biden Plan on Labor Force and GDP

ELs     .15 .25
Reduction in Child Care Costs (%) 65 65
Implied Rise (%) in Labor Supply:
 Mothers (Children < age 13) 10 17
All Females 3 5
All Workers 1.5 2.5
Implied Rise (%) in GDP .9 1.5

Next, we calculate the reduction in child care costs that the Biden plan would generate. Since it effectively reduces child care costs by 100 percent for low-income families (those with 75 percent or less of median family income), by 82 percent for middle-income families (those with incomes of 75 to 150 percent), and by zero for high-income families (with incomes 150 percent of the median or higher); a weighted average of these reductions comes to a 65 percent decrease, which we use with both elasticity estimates.

The elasticities imply that such a reduction in child care costs would generate increases in labor supply of 10 percent and 17 percent for mothers of younger children – i.e., those at ages 12 or less. In both cases, we assume that these increases could apply to labor force participation (or the extensive margin of labor supply) or to full-time work among those in the labor force (the intensive margin), or both – neither study estimates elasticities separately for the two kinds of responses.

Since the mothers of younger children constitute approximately 28 percent of all women, the predicted impacts on the employment of all women are about 3 and 5 percent respectively, while predicted impacts on all employment (including both men and women) are about half as large – or 1.5 to 2.5 percent. (Note that our estimates of the increase in female labor force participation are in the same range as the gap in this same metric between the U.S. and other advanced countries that provide such child care assistance.)

Finally, using .6 as the labor share of GDP, we predict that such labor supply increases would raise GDP by .9 to 1.5 percent.

And What About Inflation?

Would this increase in potential GDP reduce inflation? If BBB had passed a year ago, it might have dampened current inflationary pressures this year and next. But by how much? And what if it were to pass this year?

The current annual inflation rate is 6.5 to 8.3 percent (as measured by the PCE inflation index and the CPI-U respectively). The current inflation rate is driven primarily by three factors: a) supply shocks to food, energy and other goods and services, driven by supply chain problems and the war between Russia and Ukraine; b) excess demand (relative to supply or potential GDP) for good and services, associated with the accumulated savings of households from pandemic stimulus and relief along with the release of pent-up demand post-pandemic; and c) some specific labor market factors that reduced the supply of labor.

Regarding the labor market, Domash and Summers (2022) recently suggested that nearly 7 million workers were “missing” in the labor market at the end of 2021, though that number has recently dropped to just under 5 million (or about 3 percent of the labor force). These workers have “gone missing” for a number of reasons including an aging population (some of whom are retiring earlier than in the past), less immigration, vaccine mandates, higher reservation wages (or greater choosiness about jobs), reduced incentives to work (due to the large cash benefits provided by the various pandemic relief bills and household savings that accumulated when spending was restrained by the pandemic), and Covid-related health concerns. Many women stayed home with their children during this period, and some have not yet returned to employment – perhaps for other reasons (like their own greater choosiness). But they are now a small fraction of the “missing workers.”

Child care subsidies could, in principle, have bolstered women’s employment, and reduced the number of “missing workers.”  Indeed, an increase in labor force activity of 1.5 to 2.5 percent associated with the kind of child care subsidies proposed by the Administration would by itself offset much of the “missing worker” effect that Domash and Summers estimate.

By how much would this reduce inflation now? That’s hard to estimate. We make a number of strong assumptions to very roughly estimate that labor supply effects on inflation might have been reduced by under 1 percentage point had more child care assistance been available and raised female labor force participation as a result. Subsidies and higher earnings would also bolster family income and increase aggregate demand along with supply, thus further reducing the negative impact on inflation, although we believe the labor supply effect on inflation could be larger than the demand effect.

Also, there would be significant time lags between the passage of the legislation and the increased labor force activity. It would take time for the federal government to distribute the subsidies, allow families to make alternative arrangements for their children, and have women find new employment (and perhaps careers). In addition, there is currently a shortage of child care workers, which might dissipate with higher pay for these workers but would also take time and the kind of new resources proposed by the Administration to bolster the supply of child care workers.

Of course, the Fed’s battle with inflation will take time as well. The Congressional Budget Office projects that inflation will not decline substantially until 2023 and will not reach the Fed’s 2 percent target until the end of 2024, with much uncertainty on the timing and degree of economic contraction that will have to occur.

All of this implies that, had Congress passed BBB in 2021, we likely would have begun to see its effects on inflation this year and over the next few. Under this scenario, the Fed might not have needed to contract the growth of aggregate demand as much. Passing a child care bill in 2022 would further delay any effects. In short, any new child care spending would help fight inflation, but only gradually and by a small amount.

So, when President Biden claimed that child care subsidies would reduce inflation, he was not completely wrong. And perhaps he had something else in mind: not just its macroeconomic effects, but rather the simple fact that the subsidies for child care would leave families with more money to spend on other things. Given the data reviewed above on the costs of care, this point should not be overlooked. If a 6 percent inflation rate increases how much a family has to pay for all of its expenses from, say, $50,000 to $53,000 but child care costs are reduced by $10,000, that family is clearly better off. The subsidies offset the effects of inflation rather than addressing it head-on.

Why Investing in Child Care and Pre-K Remains Important

Child care subsidies along with universal pre-k may not do much to address the currently “missing workers” in the labor market, or even to dampen inflation in the longer run, since that will depend on the Fed’s success in restraining overall demand. But they have an important role to play in addressing the longer-term problems that have caused female labor force activity in the US to stagnate over the last two decades, and to remain well below the rates achieved in other industrial countries. This, in turn, would raise family income as well as output and growth for the overall economy.

And universal pre-K would have its own positive effects on the lives of children. It would improve their early skills, raise their future educational attainment, and improve their lifetime earnings. This would also make them more productive, and add even more to the growth of the nation’s economy over time.

Conclusions

As we have indicated, the strongest case for funding child care is not the problem of high inflation, where its effects would be limited and uncertain. The more important need is to address the causes of the long-term shortfall of women with young children in the labor force, which enacting the Biden proposal would do.

Although the combined effects of more child care assistance and free pre-K on inflation in the short-run are likely small, they are almost surely in the right direction. Moreover, by substantially reducing the costs of care, they would provide families with more income with which to offset the higher costs of food, energy, and other items.  Most importantly, these policies would raise labor force participation and GDP over the longer run. Add to that their effects on children’s life trajectories, and they are a triple winner. Though perhaps too ambitious for the current political moment, the potential gains of this broader package of policies should not be forgotten.


The Brookings Institution is financed through the support of a diverse array of foundations, corporations, governments, individuals, as well as an endowment.  A list of donors can be found in our annual reports published online here. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions in this report are solely those of its author(s) and are not influenced by any donation.

  • Footnotes
    1. We assume, along with the Administration, that any new policy package would be fully paid for. Any new revenue generated by the policies would thus serve to reduce existing deficits, other things equal.  
    2. For another view, see Aaronson and Alba (2021).
    3. For the list of  OECD countries included in the ranking, see Blau and Kahn (2013). Data for 2020 was retrieved from OECD.Stat database. 
    4. Families with employed mothers are more likely to rely on non-parental care. On average, less-educated parents are more likely to rely on their own care while more-educated parents are more likely to pay, perhaps because they can better afford it (and the quality of center-based care is often higher, according to Sarah Flood et al. (2022)).
    5. The NWLC/Columbia estimate of maternal labor supply elasticity is an average of two different methods, where the first draws (as we do) from Morrissey’s paper and the second simulates labor force activity and employment among mothers by assuming such activity would match those of mothers with older children (ages 13-17) with similar characteristics. The latter method generates higher elasticities, and the average of the two is higher as well.
    6. The calculation assumes annual child care costs of $12,000 for very young children and $10,000 for those over age 6 in the absence of the Biden plan.
    7. Mothers with children under the age of 13 represent about 28 percent of all prime-age women.
    8. From January thru April 2022, the labor force and employment have risen by about 3 million workers.
    9.  We make the admittedly strong assumption that labor market factors account for 2-3 percentage points – or about a third – of current inflation (with aggregate demand and supply shocks in the goods market accounting for the other two-thirds). Then, we make the further assumption that reductions in the labor force account for half of the labor market factors and workers being choosier account for the other half. In other words, we assume the reduction in the labor force currently boosts inflation by 1 to 1.5 percentage points. What follows is that rising labor supply from additional child care (if it had been enacted earlier) could reduce inflation in the short term by .66 to 1 percentage point.
    10. This assumption is based on the notion that the plan should be fiscally neutral plan (as originally envisioned by the Administration), with higher tax revenues offsetting the increase in spending (although those receiving the subsidies likely have a higher propensity to spend than those paying the taxes). In addition, not all of any new or freed-up family income would be spent, especially with household balance sheets still in good shape after the pandemic. And we believe that relieving the labor bottlenecks in key sectors by a certain percentage might well have larger impacts on inflation than a boost in aggregate demand of the same modest amount.