Sections

Commentary

Federal Reserve Independence in the Aftermath of the Financial Crisis: Should We Be Worried?

Editor’s Note: The following comments were delivered on a panel of the National Association for Business Economics at the American Economic Association Annual Meetings on January 4, 2013.

We are going through extraordinary period in business cycles and central banking. The too-calm, too-confident, veneer of the so-called Great Moderation was shattered by the worst financial crisis in 80 years. The Federal Reserve, indeed central banks all over the industrial world, have taken extraordinary actions in response to make sure this crisis not followed by an economic result like that of the 1930s.

The Federal Reserve expanded access to the discount window for banks, and it opened credit facilities to nonbanks for the first time since the 1930s, including in a few cases to help stabilize or facilitate the takeover of systemically important institutions at risk of failure that would have further destabilized the financial system. The Federal Reserve aggressively reduced short-term rates to zero and then, to spur growth, has worked to reduce intermediate- and long-term rates even further by greatly expanding its balance sheet with purchases of long-term securities and by issuing guidance about the future path of short-term rates. And it has addressed perceived clogs in the transmission of monetary policy by intervening directly in government guaranteed mortgage market—taking a hand in credit allocation where markets are not functioning well. Other central banks in industrial countries that have been hit by crisis in recent years have taken comparable, unconventional, steps to stabilize markets and encourage growth. We are in uncharted territory—both in our understanding of economic developments and of the policy response.

Naturally, understandably, and appropriately, these circumstances have increased the scrutiny of central banks, including the Federal Reserve, raising questions about the goals, governance and accountability of these institutions. This panel has been asked whether we should we be worried that this scrutiny will result in an erosion of independence. To foreshadow my answer: these actions should not and need not lead to a loss of monetary policy independence, but we need to be vigilant because risk factors have increased.

When discussing central bank independence, it’s important to draw two key distinctions about what we mean. The first distinction concerns functions performed by the central bank. With regard to independence, our main focus has been on the setting of monetary policy, not regulatory policy. In this regard, the Federal Reserve has always lived with a bifurcated regime. The Regulatory functions of the Federal Reserve have involved a very high degree of cooperation and coordination with other agencies. Major decisions are arrived at jointly by several agencies. And those decisions are subject to examination and oversight by the General Accountability Office of the Congress.

The cooperative character of bank regulation is made necessary by the balkanized US regulatory system, with many different agencies having a hand in regulation and supervision of the financial system. It also reflects the nature of the actions taken. Regulation is necessary to offset the moral hazard created by the safety net and deal with externalities. But it involves elements of credit allocation, it constrains private decisions, and it affects the relative positions of individual firms. And it can have consequences for the public purse if regulation and supervision are not effective enough at constraining risk. Some degree of independence from political pressure is helpful in carrying out these tasks, but they may not lend themselves to the same arms-length relationship to elected representatives as does monetary policy.

The conduct of monetary policy has enjoyed considerably more, but still limited, independence. Within monetary policy, it is useful to distinguish goal from instrument independence. Goals for policy are and should be set in the democratic process by elected representatives. But independence is critical in the setting of the instruments to achieve these goals. Central banks should be held accountable for outcomes, not inputs. Instrument independence is necessary to overcome the short-term perspective of politicians, who are more interested in boosting growth for the next election and less focused on the longer-term inflationary consequences of such actions; across time and countries there is plenty of evidence that less independence is correlated with higher inflation.

Even instrument independence not absolute. Instrument settings will always be subject to political pressure and discussion. Moreover, some control is exercised through the appointments process, which for the Chairman occurs every four years. But an independent central bank—one that has been insulated from these pressures–doesn’t need to follow the politicians’ instructions; it should resist where those desires are inconsistent with its own views of how to achieve the objectives it has been given.

In considering whether Federal Reserve independence is likely to be threatened by the nature and aggressive character of its recent actions it’s important to keep in mind that there is no necessary connection between recent actions and future loss of independence. This is a decision for Congress to make legislatively, and it needs to understand the costs and benefits from any erosion of independence. Moreover, concern about a potential mistake by Congress in this regard is not a reason for the Federal Reserve to hold back on using the tools Congress has given it to accomplish the objectives Congress has set. The Federal Reserve needs to keep explaining why it considers its actions to have been consistent with furthering its objectives, and that that any fiscal risk incurred or credit allocation affected by its actions has been necessary to achieve its legislated objectives and has been a temporary function of an extraordinary situation. We can see from what is going on in Japan right now that perceptions of timidity and caution also have the potential to threaten independence.

But a number of risk factors suggest extra vigilance will be called for over coming years to preserve the appropriate degree of Federal Reserve independence. First, an era of polarization of political discourse has not proven conducive to a reasoned discussion of monetary policy and the pros and cons of independence. Exhibit one in this regard would be the debates in the Republican primaries with candidates competing as to how rapidly they would “fire” Ben Bernanke, with one characterizing a policy disagreement as “almost treasonable”. Also discouraging was the unprecedented letter from Republican congressional leaders to the Federal Reserve in September 2011 trying to dictate an instrument setting—the management of its portfolio. And, as I’ll underline in a second, we haven’t yet heard from the forces that might eventually be aroused by exit from these policies.

Second, the Federal Reserve has had some powers trimmed in Dodd-Frank, suggesting an erosion of trust and deference by lawmakers. The restrictions apply to its authority to lend to non-bank institutions under 13-3 of the Federal Reserve Act, and include an obligation to get the approval of the Secretary of the Treasury even for widely available facilities. In addition, against the recommendation of the Federal Reserve, the Congress mandated the publication of the names of all borrowers at the discount window—bank and nonbank– no later than two years after they borrow. So far, the instrument independence of the Federal Reserve in monetary policy per se has not been abridged in any way, but it may be that the Federal Reserve’s views carry less weight than they did before the crisis.

Third, although in recent years the political blowback mainly has come from those who say they are worried about inflation, the major challenge to independence is likely to come from those concerned about unemployment as the Federal Reserve exits from unconventional policies. At some point the Federal Reserve will need to tighten policy to keep inflation from rising persistently above its price stability target. It will need to raise rates and begin returning its portfolio towards its prior plain vanilla size and composition. The turn toward tightening is always a difficult decision—and subject to second-guessing in the political sphere—but it will be even tougher after long period of weak growth and unprecedented policy actions.

It will be a complex exit involving many steps—with lots of opportunity for kibitzing and objecting over a long period. It will ultimately involve a sharp correction in long-term rates—a reversal of a negative term premium as well as upward adjustment in expected short-term rates. It will entail withdrawal of special support for the mortgage market. As long-term rates rise the Federal Reserve will have mark to market loses on its balance sheet. These loses are not a threat to the Federal Reserve’s ability to tighten or its independence so long as cash flow is positive, but the loses could be used as a political weapon. The main tightening tool will be increases in the interest rate paid to banks on their deposits at the Federal Reserve, further damping Federal Reserve profits; this is a tool well known in other jurisdictions, but is new for the US. The size of the portfolio shouldn’t impede ability to tighten, given this new tool, but a huge volume of reserves could make control over the federal funds rate less precise than it has been in the past. Finally, in light of the apparent inability of the Congress and administration to deal with longer-term budget issues, the rise in rates could be occurring in context of still-unsustainable path for budget and debt, and higher rates will underline that issue and make it worse. This will be another source of unhappiness in political sphere.

Fourth, the Federal Reserve, like many other central banks, has been given added responsibilities in regulation and supervision. These responsibilities include a key role in macroprudential regulation, with responsibility for protecting the overall stability of the financial system. Carrying out this regulation already involves a differential impact on some organizations—those identified as systemically important. It could also entail tightening up when credit is growing too fast and imbalances are seen to be developing—another form of taking away the punch bowl as the party gets going—for example through raising the countercyclical capital buffer under Basel III. This will not be popular with those drinking the punch. In the years leading up to the crisis we saw considerable political resistance to even mild forms of tighter policy, for example with respect to commercial real estate lending. The risk is that greater scrutiny and criticism of this aspect of Federal Reserve activity could spillover to monetary policy. It is important to retain the bifurcation—the differences in governance and accountability for regulation and monetary policy.

But macroprudential policy could also protect monetary policy independence. It reduces the need for the Federal Reserve to use monetary policy to deal with bubbles, imbalances, or a build up of leverage. It now has another tool to apply to these. Monetary policy can be focused on price stability and maximum employment and more readily held accountable for those less diffuse goals than for “financial Stability”. More focused goals and accountability should support retaining monetary policy independence.

The most immediate threat to appropriate independence now would seem to be the proposal to allow GAO to audit of monetary policy—to remove the exemption for monetary policy that has existed since the 1970s. The expanded GAO audit authority would be another avenue to bring pressure on the Federal Reserve’s monetary policy—perhaps trying to delay actions pending a GAO study. Of course, such pressure can and should be ignored when the Federal Reserve is convinced it is doing the right thing to accomplish its legislated objectives. But extending the GAO audit moves the needle, however slightly, in the wrong direction when it will be important to protect the Federal Reserve’s instrument independence for exit. And it erodes that distinction between the governance of regulatory and monetary policy functions that seems so useful to make.

Federal Reserve monetary policy independence will be critical to preserve over next few years. There’s just too much history behind the concern that less independence leads to higher inflation over time. I hope all economists can agree on this—whatever they think of the actual policy actions that have been undertaken. The views of economists could be important in any discussion of this subject that might occur.