What happened on Nov. 5: A deep dive into the results of the presidential and congressional races

LIVE

What happened on Nov. 5: A deep dive into the results of the presidential and congressional races
Sections

Research

Revisiting Sovereign Bankruptcy

Bankruptcy graffiti on wall

Editor’s Note: This report was written by members of the Committee on International Economic Policy and Reform, a non-partisan, independent group of experts, comprised of academics and former government and central bank officials.

sovereign debt

Sovereign debt crises occur regularly and often
violently. The recent debt crisis in Greece almost
led to the collapse of the Euro. Yet there
is no legally and politically recognized procedure
for restructuring the debt of bankrupt sovereigns.
Procedures of this type have been periodically debated—
most recently, about a decade ago, when
IMF management proposed a global sovereign
debt restructuring mechanism (SDRM). They have
so far been rejected. Countries have been reluctant
to give up power to supranational rules or institutions.
Creditors and debtors have felt that there
were sufficient instruments for addressing debt
crises at hoc. Importantly, there were also fears
that making debt easier to restructure would raise
the costs and reduce the amounts of sovereign
borrowing in many countries. This was perceived
to be against the interests of both the providers of
both creditors and major borrowers.

This year’s CIEPR report argues that both the
nature and our understanding of sovereign debt
problems have changed in ways that create a much
stronger case for an orderly sovereign bankruptcy
regime today than ten years ago.

  • Pre-crisis policy mistakes—and in particular,
    the tendency of domestic policymakers
    to overborrow or pay too little attention
    to private debt accumulation that
    might turn public—are now recognized to
    be a much more severe problem for borrowing
    countries than the costs or limited
    availability of private financing. Far from
    being a problem, proposals that would
    limit the ability to borrow for countries
    with poor policies are a good thing.

  • Recent court rulings—particularly a recent
    U.S. ruling that gives “holdout creditors”
    that decline a restructuring offer the right
    to interfere with payments to the creditors
    that accept such an offer. This will complicate
    efforts to resolve future debt crises on
    an ad hoc basis.

  • Sovereign debt crises are no longer just a
    problem in emerging markets, but a core
    concern in advanced countries as well—
    particularly in the Euro area. If the Euro
    is to survive, this will require both better
    ways to resolve debt crises and stronger,
    market-based incentives that prevent debt
    problems from occurring in the first place.

To address these problems, the report presents
policy proposals at two levels: for the Euro area,
and globally.

The current financial architecture in the Euro area is inadequate in this respect, because its main pillar—the European Stability Mechanism (ESM)—is not set up to deal with unsustainable debt.

The Euro area differs from other integrated regions
both in that its members have fewer instruments
to deal with debt crises—they cannot
devalue or inflate—and because a crisis in one
member can have catastrophic consequences for
others (by threatening the common currency).
This requires both a mechanism for the orderly
resolution of debt crises and stronger incentives to
prevent them. The current financial architecture in
the Euro area is inadequate in this respect, because
its main pillar—the European Stability Mechanism
(ESM)—is not set up to deal with unsustainable
debt. If it is used even when there are significant
concerns about the ability of borrowers to repay
their debts, it will become source of transfers, rather
than just crisis lending.

These problems could be addressed via an amendment
of the ESM treaty that encourages and legitimizes—
both legally and politically—debt restructuring
in unsustainable debt cases.

  • First, assets and revenues of countries
    undertaking a debt restructuring would
    be deemed immune from legal action by
    holdouts if a restructuring is approved by
    the ESM.

  • Second, the treaty would require a debt restructuring
    as a condition for ESM lending
    when national debts exceed a pre-set level.
    This should be higher than the Maastricht
    limit of 60 percent of GDP, but not so high
    as to render the constraint meaningless. In
    the Euro area, this may mean a level about
    1 ½ times the Maastricht limit. The presence
    of such a debt threshold would help
    differentiate borrowing costs in normal
    times based on the strength of economic
    policies. At the same time, it would protect
    ESM resources and Euro area taxpayers,
    and prevent extreme adjustments of
    public finances at the expense of citizens
    who usually have little control over policy
    mistakes leading to excessive sovereign
    debt.

Importantly, Euro area countries must be given a
chance to deal with legacy debt before this regime
is introduced. For countries significantly above
the future upper debt threshold, this will require
a judgment of whether debt can be reduced below
the limit within a reasonable time frame. Where
the answer is no, the Euro area needs to make a
choice between an upfront restructuring – backed
by the ESM – and extra support, for example, in
the form of providing a joint and several guarantee
on new debt issuance as long as countries adhere
to an agreed fiscal consolidation path.

Recent court rulings encouraging holdouts, discouraging creditor participation in debt exchange offers, and bringing into question the IMF’s priority status, will make this problem worse.

At the global level, the relatively small size of the
IMF, its de facto priority and its track record in
getting repaid make it less likely that crisis lending
will turn into transfers. However, experience
shows that incentives are stacked against the
timely recognition and restructuring of unsustainable
debts. Recent court rulings encouraging
holdouts, discouraging creditor participation in debt exchange offers, and bringing into question
the IMF’s priority status, will make this problem
worse. To address this without allowing sovereigns
to frivolously repudiate their debts, two alternative
mechanisms are proposed.

  • A coordinated introduction of a strong
    form of “collective action clauses” in sovereign
    bond contract, namely, provisions
    that allow for the restructuring of bonded
    debt with the agreement of a supermajority
    of creditors across all bonds. 

  • The creation of a Sovereign Debt Adjustment
    Facility by the International Monetary
    Fund, which would combine IMF
    lending with debt restructuring. A set
    of clearly defined ex ante criteria, analogous
    to those used in the HIPC initiative,
    would need to be developed to steer high
    debt countries towards this facility. An
    amendment of the IMF articles would ensure
    that the assets of countries using this
    facility would be shielded from holdouts
    if a supermajority of creditors agrees to a
    restructuring.

The main difference between the two proposals is
that the second would do more to correct biases
that delay necessary debt restructuring. Furthermore,
while both would deal with the holdout
problem in the long run, the IMF-based proposal
would have immediate effects, while better collective
action clauses would become effective only
gradually, as existing debt is replaced by newly issued
debt.

The world is currently less equipped to handle
problems of unsustainable debt than at any time
since the 1930s. At the same time, the extent of
these problems has grown. Reform proposals that
could address them have become more mature and
more targeted, and arguments that led to the rejection
of analogous proposals 10 years ago no longer
apply. It is time for policy makers to tackle the central
problems head on.