Sections

Research

BPEA | 1988 No. 1

The New Keynesian Economics and the Output-Inflation Trade-Off

David H. Romer,
David H. Romer
David H. Romer Nonresident Senior Fellow - Economic Studies
Laurence Ball, and
BPEA Ball
Laurence Ball Professor of Economics - Johns Hopkins University
N. Gregory Mankiw
N. Gregory Mankiw Robert M. Beren Professor of Economics - Harvard University
Discussants: Andrew K. Rose,
Andrew K. Rose University of California, Berkeley
George A. Akerlof, and
George A. Akerlof Daniel E. Koshland, Sr. Distinguished Professor Emeritus of Economics - University of California, Berkeley
Janet L. Yellen
Janet Yellen headshot
Janet L. Yellen United States Secretary of the Treasury - United States Department of the Treasury, Former Distinguished Fellow in Residence - Economic Studies

1988, No. 1


IN THE EARLY 1980s, the Keynesian view of business cycles was in trouble. The problem was not new empirical evidence against Keynesian theories, but weakness in the theories themselves. According to the Keynesian view, fluctuations in output arise largely from fluctuations in nominal aggregate demand. These changes in demand have real effects because nominal wages and prices are rigid. But in Keynesian models of the 1970s, the crucial nominal rigidities were assumed rather than explained-assumed directly, as in disequilibrium models, or introduced through theoretically arbitrary assumptions about labor contracts. Indeed, it was clearly in the interests of agents to eliminate the rigidities they were assumed to create. If wages, for example, were set above the market-clearing level, firms could increase profits by reducing wages. Microeconomics teaches us to reject models in which, as Robert Lucas puts it, “there are $500 bills on the sidewalk.” Thus the 1970s and early 1980s saw many economists turn away from Keynesian theories and toward new classical models with flexible wages and prices.